Sins of the Father

Read Sins of the Father Online

Authors: Conor McCabe

BOOK: Sins of the Father
3.26Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub

CONTENTS

     
Title Page

     
Acknowledgements

     
Introduction

1   Housing

2   Agriculture

3   Industry

4   Finance

5   From Bank Guarantee to Bailout

6   The Other Side of the Show

     
Conclusion

     
Notes

     
Bibliography

     
Copyright

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

Special thanks to:

Beth Amphlett; John Bissett; Donagh Brennan; Kevin and Jack Cleary; John Cleary; Ronan Colgan; Mel Corry; Mags Crean; Rudi Deda; Vicky Donnelly; Ciarán Finnegan; Daithí Flynn; Brian Forbes; Colm Hall; Brian Hanley; Donal Higgins; Darren Hudson; Linda Howard; Frank Keoghan; Seán Lucey; Kathleen Lynch; Mark Malone; Donal McCarthy; Eugene McCarthy; Padraig Walsh McCarthy; Niamh McCrea; Scott Millar; Marie Moran; Moira Murphy; Tom Murray; Stevie Nolan; Donnacha O’Briain; Claire O’Connell; Tom O’Connor; Cathal O’Lorcawn; Mick O’Reilly; Miriam Guillén Pardo; Aubrey Robinson; Brian Stafford; Michael Taft; the staff of the National Library of Ireland and in particular Gerard Kavanagh; my brothers Aiden, Niall, Paul and Gerard, and my sisters Kathleen, Nora, Sandra and Siobhan; and Joanne Walsh.

INTRODUCTION

There have been more than a few attempts to explain why the Irish banking crisis developed the way it did, and the argument that it was due to a breakdown in moral standards is quite a popular one. The journalist Fintan O’Toole was explicit in this regard when he wrote in 2009 that, ‘The absence of a sense of propriety, of restraint and of right and wrong’ on the part of the bankers ‘was not just obnoxious, it was economically disastrous.’
i
The Irish Times
talked of a ‘frightening lack of morality’ within Anglo Irish Bank, the most indebted of the Irish institutions, and how the actions of its chairman ‘cast a shadow over the ethical culture of the bank he ran for most of the past 33 years.’
ii
The newspaper’s senior business correspondent, Arthur Beesley, said that the directors of Irish Life and Permanent inhabit an ‘ethical cocoon in which the sense of right and wrong is at odds with standards in the outside world’, while the economist Brian Lucey talked of the immorality of the government’s actions in pouring money into Anglo Irish Bank in a desperate attempt to keep it going as a business concern.
iii

Yet, the banking crisis in Ireland was not caused by pockets of immorality in an otherwise reasonably well-functioning system. The ruthless pursuit of profit is not personal; that is the way business works. And what is condemned as immoral in times of crisis is often praised as savvy and pragmatic in times of prosperity.
iv
Similarly, there is nothing particularly unique about the ethical cocoons of Irish bankers, their frightening lack of morality, lack of restraint or sense of propriety. This was a worldwide financial crisis, after all, not a regional or a Celtic one. In other words, it was not the implosion of speculative debt but the ability to transfer that debt wholesale onto the shoulders of the State which marked out Irish bankers as a step above their worldwide contemporaries.

The decision by the Irish government on 30 September 2008 to guarantee almost all the liabilities of six Irish financial institutions was not an economic decision but an exercise in power. ‘The deeper truth exposed by the present crisis,’ wrote the journalist and politician Shane Ross, ‘is that Ireland harbours more powerful forces than Fianna Fáil.’
v
And while this is true, the purpose of this book is not to show that banks and property developers are indeed powerful in Ireland but to explore why that is the case. What is it about the Irish economy that has made financial and property speculation a core activity and not, say, fisheries or gas? Why were builders and insurance salesmen fêted as entrepreneurs, while indigenous exporters outside of agriculture and tourism struggled to find support? How did this situation arise, and how deep are its roots?

Put as concisely as possible, the type of business activities which dominated the Irish economy in the twentieth century – cattle exports to Britain and financial investment in London; the development of green-field sites and the construction of factories and office buildings to facilitate foreign industrial and commercial investment; the birth of the suburbs and subsequent housing booms predicated on an expanding urban workforce – saw the development of an indigenous moneyed class based around cattle, construction and banking. These sectional interests were able to control successive government policy, much to the detriment of the rest of the economy, which had to rely on whatever scraps it could pick up from quasi-committed multinationals and government-funded grants and tax breaks. In 2008 the construction and banking sectors of that class closed ranks in order to protect themselves from oblivion, resulting in the bank guarantee and the creation of the National Asset Management Agency.

The power to do that did not develop overnight. In order to find the reason why that class was able to wield such influence at such short notice, we are going to have to dig. This book sets out a historical analysis of the events of September 2008 in order to achieve that objective.

History provides a canvas wide and deep enough to enable us to see the economic and political mechanisms, the machine itself, in motion. By looking at the way the Irish economy actually works – the deep structures and investment strategies – the government’s response to the banking crisis, despite its inherent insanity, starts to make sense. The logic behind it reveals itself. It is still deeply shocking, but it was not the result of a few bad apples.

The plan of the book is, hopefully, straightforward enough. There are four chapters dealing with the development of the Irish economy, and two chapters on the crisis itself. It starts with housing, as the subject is saturated with so many myths and half-truths that it demands a factual analysis. There is no Irish property-owning gene. It is not part of our DNA. Home ownership outside of rural areas is a relatively new phenomenon. Chapter Two deals with cattle, as it is simply impossible to discuss the history of the Irish economy without discussing beef and live exports. Up until the 1980s, cattle was to Ireland what the car industry was to Detroit and, although the Irish Free State gained partial independence in 1922, its economy, via the cattle industry, remained intertwined with that of the UK.

The structural problems related to that situation – an independent country with a regional economy – had an influence on the so-called Whitaker/Lemass revolution in the 1950s and the superficial industrialization of the Irish economy in the decade which followed in its wake. Ireland imported foreign industry as a substitute for indigenous industrial growth. This is also the period when we see a new type of Irish businessman – the speculative builder and financier – come to the fore. The banking system is opened up and liberalized. By the late 1980s foreign industrial investment has stalled. The government decides to extend its low corporation tax rate to financial as well as industrial exports. The International Financial Services Centre is born. Ireland becomes a tax haven, with minimum regulation and oversight. By the time the last of the barriers to speculative financial trading are lifted in the US, Ireland is more than ready to take the world’s money. In 2008 the veneer of cheap credit suddenly fades, leaving the shaky edifice of the Irish economy exposed.

It is hoped that these six chapters will shine a light on the reasons why Ireland has the businesses it has, and why banks and speculators wield so much power and influence. It is only by acknowledging the facts of our situation that we can even begin to attempt to do something about it. This book is presented as a small contribution to that process.

1
HOUSING

A lot of what we consider to be normal and natural about Irish housing dates from the 1920s. The first garden suburbs were built during this time, with significant subsidies to private builders backed up by a government policy that promoted home ownership above tackling the tenements and slums. It was a policy which favoured the middle classes and the higher-paid, skilled members of the working class.
1
However, while suburbia can be traced back to the turn of the last century, it took decades for this type of planning to become the norm. Issues such as cost, distance, work and community all acted against these moves towards the periphery. In other words, there is nothing natural about suburbia. There is nothing normal about living significant distances from one’s place of employment, even if it is normal to us today. The semi-detached with a garden and a fence was not an organic or spontaneous development. As with so many things regarding large-scale societal development, it began with an idea and was pushed through by government, through the use of incentives and the elimination of alternatives.

In 1898, an English civil servant produced a book entitled
Tomorrow: A Peaceful Path to Real Reform
, in which he described his vision for the cities of the future. His name was Ebenezer Howard and his publication proved to be quite popular. It was quickly followed by a second edition, which he called
Garden Cities of Tomorrow
, the name by which it is commonly known today. Throughout the nineteenth century, the apparently insurmountable problems of urban sprawl – poverty, dirt, disease and crime – were subject to a multitude of official reports and parliamentary enquiries. Rural dwellers were regarded as stronger and healthier than their urban cousins who, it was believed, suffered from both physical and moral decay. Cities were depraved and corrupt, while the countryside was honest and noble. However, it was seen as well-nigh impossible to have an industrial society without urbanisation. It was unfortunate, but the stench and decay of the modern city were simply part of the sad but necessary price of progress. Its extremities could be tempered, but never eradicated.

Howard thought otherwise. He wanted to merge the benefits of the city with those of the countryside through the creation of satellite towns of no more than 30,000 people and 1,000 acres, each surrounded by an agricultural green-belt of 5,000 acres and 2,000 people, and linked to the main metropolis by quick and efficient public transport. This ‘town-country’ fusion would offer the individual and his family such opportunities for employment and personal advancement as available in any town, while also providing the benefits of fresh air and bright sunshine via the city parks and nearby countryside. He wanted to show how, in his ‘town-county’ cities, ‘equal, nay better, opportunities of social intercourse may be enjoyed than are enjoyed in any crowded city, while yet the beauties of nature may encompass and enfold each dweller therein’.
2
Over the next sixty years, Howard’s vision of ‘garden cities’ mutated into the suburbs of today.

It is not a coincidence that the dominant form of housing in modern Ireland, i.e. one-family occupancy with a garden in suburbia, can be traced back to a small book by an English reformist. When it came to housing and planning, Ireland frequently looked across the sea to Britain, and this influence was present in Irish newspapers, journals and pamphlets, as well as official reports, planning committees, and architectural design. From the 1880s onwards, the House of Commons passed legislation which gave a notable amount of Irish rural labourers ‘high-quality, low-cost social housing and also created a social housing sector which was precociously large for its time’.
3
These acts, along with the 1890 Housing of the Working Classes Act, provided the underlying framework for much of social housing schemes which were built post-independence.

The reason for this advancement in rural housing was not altruistic but political. The Irish Parliamentary Party used land reform as a tactic in its campaign for self-government. The transfer of land ownership from landlords to farmer-tenants led to demands for a similar franchise on the part of agricultural labourers, who were excluded from land reform, but who were too much of a social force to be ignored by the Parliamentary Party. From 1883 to 1906, some 20,000 agricultural labourers’ cottages were built by local authorities.
4
Construction rose to new levels after the introduction of the 1906 Labourers (Ireland) Act.
5
By 1922, an estimated 50,582 cottages had been completed under the various Acts. This accounted for about 10 per cent of the total rural stock. By way of contrast, during the same period only 8,861 dwellings had been completed by urban councils. This was despite the fact that Ireland’s rural population was declining while its urban population was increasing.

Other books

Surrender, Dorothy by Meg Wolitzer
The Ghost Belonged to Me by Richard Peck
Letters to Nowhere by Julie Cross
Come Dancing by Leslie Wells
Untamed by Emilia Kincade
Prophecy by Ellen Oh
Rogue Elements by Hector Macdonald