Read The Alchemists: Three Central Bankers and a World on Fire Online

Authors: Neil Irwin

Tags: #Business & Economics, #Economic History, #Banks & Banking, #Money & Monetary Policy

The Alchemists: Three Central Bankers and a World on Fire (37 page)

BOOK: The Alchemists: Three Central Bankers and a World on Fire
2.43Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub
ads

In the Federal Reserve System, as in all modern central banks, it is a committee that formally decides how to best steer an economy toward the happy middle ground between inflation and recession. But even though the Fed chairman has only one vote out of twelve, his true power goes far beyond that. He sets the agenda and frames the options on the table. He guides the discussion toward directions he believes useful and away from those he disfavors. And seven of the twelve voters at each FOMC meeting are governors based in Washington, who frequently feel an institutional loyalty to vote with the chairman even if they have reservations. Those deliberations about the Jackson Hole speech were really about Bernanke making up his mind.

Of those in the room for this innermost of circles, Warsh, a onetime investment banker turned White House staffer who had been the youngest Fed governor in history when President George W. Bush appointed him in 2006, most consistently argued against a new program of easing. What was wrong with the U.S. economy, according to Warsh’s line of reasoning, wouldn’t be fixed by pumping more money into it. There was the overhang of housing from the boom years and a glacially slow process of foreclosures that was preventing the market from clearing, the debts weighing on households, the retrenchment of state and local governments. With short-term interest rates near zero, Americans could already obtain a thirty-year fixed-rate mortgage for an interest rate of around 4.4 percent, far below any longer-term historical average, and creditworthy businesses could borrow at similarly low rates to buy equipment or build a factory.

It wasn’t at all clear that injecting an extra few hundred billion dollars into the economy would encourage more economic activity. And it would come with risks, too: If the Fed owned too much of the federal government’s debt, it might disrupt the American bond market, the biggest in the world. Would the market function properly if private buyers were essentially pushed out? Would they return once the Fed was ready to back away? Could yet another round of activism by the Fed make the central bank vulnerable to attacks by elected officials who were wary of government involvement in the economy? And could that actually undermine confidence among businesses?

As Warsh mounted those arguments against new action, Bernanke and Kohn countered with a much simpler logic. The Fed’s job, as dictated by Congress, is to try to ensure stable prices and maximum employment—the “dual mandate,” as it’s known. Prices were rising more slowly than the 2 percent that most Fed leaders viewed as stable. And the job market wasn’t rebounding anywhere near as quickly as anyone had hoped. Therefore, Bernanke and the Fed’s task was to find a way to pump more money into the economy, even if they couldn’t be sure just how much of an effect it would have.

Bernanke was in particular a subscriber to a “tipping point” theory of how the economy works. The U.S. economy is capable of growing somewhere around 2 or 2.5 percent each year simply due to an expanding labor force and rising worker productivity. That means that slower growth, if sustained, could create a vicious cycle: more people unemployed, driving down incomes, driving down demand for products, leading to more layoffs, and voilà
,
an economy back in a recession, or even an outright contraction. If the Fed could give the economy just enough of a push to get it over that 2.5 percent growth hurdle, the reverse might set in: a virtuous cycle of falling unemployment, rising incomes, more demand, and more hiring. One little nudge from the Fed might make a great deal of difference.

The most recent report on growth at the time had shown a 2.4 percent rate of expansion in the spring of 2010—in other words, right on that line where, if Bernanke’s tipping-point premise was correct, a little bit of a push in the right direction could go a long way. Yes, cheaper money might not help growth as much as it could without the counterinfluences of mortgage market dysfunction and debt overhang. But it could probably help on the margins.

And if the Fed did squeeze private investors out of the Treasury bond market, he argued, they would have to put their money elsewhere, affecting the economy through what is known as the portfolio balance channel. They might buy corporate bonds, which would mean still more money available for companies looking to expand. They might buy mortgage securities, which would make it cheaper for Americans to buy or refinance a house. Or they might invest in the stock market, pushing up share prices and, in the process, household wealth.

By the end of these sessions—half a dozen in total—Bernanke and his closest advisers had drafted a speech that laid out the decision of whether to do another round of quantitative easing as one of costs versus benefits. “As we return once again to Jackson Hole, I think we would all agree that, for much of the world, the task of economic recovery and repair remains far from complete,” Bernanke, yet again standing under the elk-antler chandeliers at the Jackson Lake Lodge, said to the 110 or so people gathered in the ballroom. Many thousands more around the world read the text of the speech as it was published simultaneously online.

Bernanke very much raised the possibility of new action but stopped far short of pledging it. “The committee is prepared to provide additional monetary accommodation through unconventional measures if it proves necessary, especially if the outlook were to deteriorate significantly . . . the issue is instead whether, at any given juncture, the benefits of each tool, in terms of additional stimulus, outweigh the associated costs or risks of using the tool.” In other words: QE2 was very much on the table, but it would only be enacted if conditions deteriorated further.

“Fed Ponders Bolder Moves” was the
Wall Street
Journal
headline; “Bernanke Pledges Dramatic Steps If Economy Worsens,” said the
Washington Post
. That was the public perception. Those who had been privy to the writing of the speech had a different view. The Fed chairman would never have said so explicitly, but from the Jackson Hole speech forward, the task at hand was to figure out how best to pump more money into the economy and build support for drastic action on the committee. The Bernanke that advisers saw in those private sessions was a man who had made up his mind that the Fed was going to do something—and something big. He just had to figure out how to make it happen.

Barely three weeks after the Jackson Hole speech, the FOMC was due to meet again, once more against a backdrop of gloomy economic news. The August jobs report, released September 3, showed another month of anemic private job creation and an unemployment rate that had ticked up to 9.6 percent, yet another sign of a sputtering economic expansion. Around the country, when the presidents of Fed banks logged in to the secure document server in advance of the September 21 FOMC meeting, they found that Option B again tilted toward easier money.

This time, at another rushed one-day (really one-morning) committee meeting, the consensus was that the apparent low inflation and weak growth warranted moving toward looser monetary policy. But there was no agreement on how to pursue it. Bernanke didn’t force the issue. Instead, he encouraged the committee members to signal the things they could agree upon in the statement released after the meeting: that inflation was “currently at levels somewhat below” what the committee views as best, and that the Fed “is prepared to provide additional accommodation if needed to support the economic recovery and to return inflation, over time, to levels consistent with its mandate.” Translation: We’re on the verge of doing something, even if we don’t know yet what it is.

Incrementalism proved a useful method for bringing more Fed policymakers around to Bernanke’s point of view. It allowed time for more evidence to mount that the economy was indeed stuck in neutral, as well as for those officials who had reservations about a new policy to believe that their concerns were given a fair hearing. Meanwhile, Bernanke’s inner circle was changing: Kohn, the walking institutional memory of the Fed, who had been right-hand man to Alan Greenspan and then vice chairman under Bernanke, had retired on September 1. Obama had appointed Janet Yellen to replace Kohn as vice chairman, and although she wouldn’t be confirmed until October 4, she had already moved to Washington. And she was decidedly dovish—one of the committee’s strongest advocates for the idea that with the economy underperforming and inflation not much of a threat, greater activism was warranted.

Bill Dudley, who had succeeded Timothy Geithner as president of the New York Fed, also believed that the central bank needed to do more to boost the economy. Even better, he knew the practical, nuts-and-bolts details of how to carry that out, which ensured that any desire to ease policy wouldn’t run up against technical problems identified by “traders,” as the New York Fed’s markets desk calls them, who buy and sell securities in order to carry out Fed policies. Dudley had previously run that operation, so he knew well what challenges awaited in execution. With Kohn gone and Warsh firmly against new monetary easing, Yellen and Dudley became Bernanke’s closest collaborators.

On October 1, Dudley gave a speech that left little doubt that something significant was on the way. Speaking to the Society of American Business Editors and Writers, he described how the Fed was failing in both encouraging job creation and in keeping inflation at its target rate, explaining how buying bonds might improve things on both fronts. He even raised a relatively controversial idea that had been often mentioned by academics but rarely by policymakers: that a central bank might respond to inflation that’s too low by allowing some period of “catch-up” inflation. He then offered a conclusion that included none of the understatement, jargon, or circumlocution that are standard whenever senior central bankers talk about what they might do. “My assessment is that both the current levels of unemployment and inflation and the timeframe over which they are likely to return to levels consistent with our mandate are unacceptable,” Dudley said. “We have tools that can provide additional stimulus at costs that do not appear to be prohibitive. Thus, I conclude that further action is likely to be warranted.”

Fed watchers in financial markets often overestimated how much FOMC members coordinate their speeches. Contrary to common assumption, presidents of the reserve banks around the country don’t generally run their speeches by Bernanke and his colleagues in Washington, let alone take marching orders. They act on their own. But when Dudley speaks, it’s a little different. By long tradition, the New York Fed chief is vice chairman of the FOMC, and with that comes a responsibility to ensure he isn’t getting too far out of step with what the majority of the committee—and its chairman—is thinking. For that reason, Dudley’s speech came very close to preannouncing QE2.

Bernanke had successfully built a consensus that some sort of easing made sense; he and his allies now set out to shift the discussion toward
how
as opposed to
whether.
As if to underscore that shift, three days after Dudley’s speech, his key deputy, Brian Sack, who ran the Fed’s markets desk and would be the official charged with carrying out the new easing program, gave a talk of his own. With the intentionally bland title “Managing the Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet,” the speech explained the technical challenges of a new round of bond purchases and how the New York Fed markets desk was overcoming them. Although Sack didn’t express his own view of whether a new purchase program was warranted the way Dudley had a few days earlier, the simple fact that he was discussing the issues involved at such length gave another hint about where the FOMC was going. After all, why spend hundreds of words explaining a policy that isn’t going to be enacted? The hawks on the committee were particularly annoyed; they were forever being told not to front-run the committee by speaking about what it might do; now Dudley and even Sack, not a member of the committee at all but a staff member, were doing just that. “It was quite upsetting to me,” said Tom Hoenig, “to have the head of the Reserve Bank of New York—and the money desk guy—out there defining what the moves are going to be.” Hoenig and others made their objections known to Bernanke. “By that time I wasn’t going to wait until [the FOMC meeting]” said the Kansas City Fed chief. “I’m pissed.”

It was a wet, cold, and gloomy New England morning when, promptly at 8:15 a.m., Boston Fed president Eric Rosengren called to order the bank’s annual research conference on October 15, 2010. Eleven years earlier, the Boston Fed had brought many of the same economists together in Woodstock, Vermont, to discuss “Monetary Policy in a Low Inflation Environment.” There, Princeton professor Ben Bernanke had argued that Japan was failing to ease monetary policy sufficiently out of “self-induced paralysis.” Now, revisiting the same topic, the question on the table was whether the Bernanke Fed was stuck in a paralysis of its own. In his keynote address, Bernanke left few doubts of where he stood. “Given the committee’s objectives, there would appear—all else being equal—to be a case for further action,” the chairman said that morning, his words carried live on all the financial news channels. Acknowledging that there can be downsides to unconventional policy steps, he added that “the Federal Reserve remains committed to pursuing policies that promote our dual objectives of maximum employment and price stability.”

Bernanke left the conference soon afterward to fly back to Washington. In the hours that followed, leading academic economists debated the theoretical challenges of easing the money supply when short-term interest rates are already at zero. The challenge of the situation that the Bank of Japan found itself in a decade earlier, and that the Fed now was grappling with, was that it couldn’t cut rates to the point where they would be low enough to stimulate investment, below the so-called zero lower bound. Some grappled with the mind-bending question of why rates
can’t
go below zero. What if the Fed tried to set a negative interest rate—that is, effectively levying a tax on savings? Said Greg Mankiw, a Harvard economist and former White House adviser, at the Boston conference, “What a depositor is going to do is say, ‘Well, if they’re going to charge me money to keep my money at the bank, I’m just going to keep my money at home,’ and the only thing you’ll generate is a demand for safe assets—and by that I mean assets that are safes because they’re going to be buying a bunch of safes so people can put their money in their safes rather than in the bank.” He added that one way around that problem, suggested by a student, would be to declare currency with certain serial numbers invalid. “I won’t say who he was,” Mankiw said. “Because he may want to be a central banker one day.”

BOOK: The Alchemists: Three Central Bankers and a World on Fire
2.43Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub
ads

Other books

Quicksilver by R.J. Anderson
The Pink and the Grey by Anthony Camber
Letting Hearts Heal by Luna Jensen
Mixed Blood by Roger Smith
Big Machine by Victor Lavalle
Exposed by Kimberly Marcus
Sati by Pike, Christopher