Read The Politics of Climate Change Online
Authors: Anthony Giddens
Energy efficiency is important to combating climate change if part of a wide-ranging policy package. If not, it can in fact directly increase emissions, since the savings made may be simply spent on other carbon-producing activities. Japan is an example of a society that has a high level of energy efficiency, but growing greenhouse gas emissions. Finally, most countries want greater energy security, except those amply provided with natural resources. Energy security can be a driving motivation for reducing emissions, but only if carefully directed to that end. Thus a country that responds to worries about energy security by turning back to coal would exacerbate global warming rather than help reduce it. Coal is the most lethal fossil fuel in terms of emissions.
Key arguments of this book are that the industrial nations must take the lead in addressing climate change and that the chances of success will depend a great deal upon
government
and
the state
. Whatever can be done through the state will in turn depend upon generating widespread political support from citizens, within the context of democratic rights and freedoms. I don't want to deny that reaching international agreements is essential, or that many other agencies, including NGOs and businesses, will play a fundamental role. However, for better or worse, the state retains many of the powers that have to be invoked if a serious impact on global warming is to be made.
What should the role of the state, as ensuring state, be? Its main function must be to act as a catalyst, as a facilitator, but certainly, as far as climate change and energy security are concerned, it has also to strive for guarantees. These are areas where solutions simply have to be found, and where there are timetables involved. If your living room is a mess, you can wait until you have time to clear it up. We can't do the same with emissions, as they pile up in the atmosphere and oil starts to run out.
These are some of the tasks in which the state has to be prime actor:
Is this all asking too much, given the fact that governments often find themselves hemmed in by the pressure of events of the day? The political theorist John Dryzek argues that the combination of capitalist markets, vested interests and state bureaucracy means that government will be âthoroughly inept when it comes to ecology'. He adds that âany redeeming features are to be found only in the possibilities they open up for their own transformation'.
1
The first comment is too dismissive, but I agree with the thrust of the second. Responding to climate change will prompt and require innovation in government itself and in the relation between the state, markets and civil society.
The above points provide the basis for this and the following two chapters. In the current one, I shall discuss what a return to planning might imply, what surveys show about public attitudes towards climate change and how we might keep the issue at the forefront of the political agenda. I will then move on to consider how consistent policy might be maintained between otherwise antagonistic political parties. In the following chapter I discuss technological innovation and what help government might play in furthering it, plus how taxation can play a role. In
chapter 7
I move on to the ticklish but necessary topic of the politics of adaptation.
Planning was in vogue for some two or three decades in Western countries after the Second World War and was, of course, the very basis of the economy in Soviet-type societies. Between 1928 and 1991, as many as 13 successive national plans were instituted in the USSR. Planning was not only in fashion, but was
de rigueur
in Western countries too for a lengthy period after the Second World War, before falling into disrepute. In 1949 the economist Evan Durbin wrote: âWe are all planners now. . . . The collapse of the popular faith in
laissez-faire
has proceeded with spectacular rapidity . . . all over the world since the War.'
2
In the post-war period, âplanning' normally meant strong central direction by the state in the interests of overall economic prosperity and social justice. In the mixed economies of the West, it signalled the nationalization of industry, especially those industries seen as strategically important, such as the energy industries, communications and iron and steel. It also referred to the creation of âplanned communities', such as ânew towns' and garden cities.
The reasons why the world retreated from planning, especially in its more centralized versions, were various. In Soviet-style society it was associated with an authoritarian, oppressive state. Even in the West many came to resent the heavy-handed outlook of government planners â faceless bureaucrats who could intervene in communities without much thought for local concerns or sensitivities. Moreover, centralized planning of the economy, supposed to overcome the irrationalities of capitalism, proved quite unable to cope with the complexities of a developed economic system. Bets were placed by governments on industries which promptly then went on to fail. Critics such as Friedrich von Hayek were proved correct when they argued that only markets can cope with the enormous numbers of on-the-ground decisions about prices and products that have to be made every moment of the day in modern economies.
3
When the counter-revolution set in, from the 1980s onwards, involving widespread privatization, coupled with
minimal macroeconomic steering, the very word âplanning' came under a shadow and has, until recently, remained there. Yet whenever we think about the future in a systematic way, in the sense of attempting to shape or guide it, planning of some sort is inevitable. The post-war period was one of reconstruction, in which large-scale investments had to be made in order to recover from a situation of immense material damage.
Many forms of planning were in fact carried on âbelow the radar' by states, even after the time at which the idea fell into disrepute. Governments have had to monitor demographic shifts, for instance, in order to plan ahead for future needs in education, health and pensions. They have had to do the same with roads and railways in terms of future projections of use. Contingency plans have to exist in case of possible disasters. Even as âplanned communities' fell out of fashion, so urban planning of one sort or another continued.
There has now to be a return to greater state interventionism, a conclusion that is reinforced by the failure of deregulation. That failure can be summed up as too much âshort-termism' and a corrosion of public institutions, coupled to a lack of controls for system risk. In terms of the economy, ways will have to be found to introduce regulation without crippling that sense of adventure and entrepreneurialism upon which a successful response to climate change will also depend. In a nutshell, overall macroeconomic steering, the main economic role of government for the past three or four decades, is no longer enough. There needs to be a greater emphasis on industrial policy. This point is obvious in the case of the fostering of low-carbon technologies, but surely must apply more broadly â although the issues involved stretch well beyond my specific concerns here. Supply-side mechanisms will continue to be vital areas for state investment, as in the case of education or the provision of infrastructure.