Volcker (46 page)

Read Volcker Online

Authors: William L. Silber

Tags: #The Triumph of Persistence

BOOK: Volcker
3.52Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub

Volcker emphasized that the “tone at the top” matters, and the FSOC agreed. Its report includes in its summary recommendations that regulators “Require banking entities to implement a robust compliance regime, including public attestation by the CEO of the regime's effectiveness.”
31
But the report went even further, suggesting that regulators consider imposing joint obligations on the board of directors and the CEO. “For example, the Board of Directors could be made responsible for … approving the compliance program … and for ensuring that these policies are adhered to in practice … The CEO could be made responsible for … communicating and reinforcing the compliance culture established by the Board of Directors.”
32

Public reaction to the report, especially commentary on the CEO's new responsibilities, pleased Volcker. Winthrop Brown, a partner at the law firm Milbank, Tweed, Hadley & McCloy, which represents banks, said, “I would be troubled if I were a chief compliance officer. It seems to be very burdensome.”
33
William Sweet, a former lawyer at the Federal Reserve and now a partner at Skadden, Arps, Slate, Meagher & Flom, said the sign-off requirement “puts the CEO in a very difficult
position.”
34
Paul Miller, an analyst at FBR Capital Markets in Arlington, Virginia, added, “The only real negative [in the report] is that CEOs must publicly attest to the rule in some way. CEOs will not like this—but nothing else is really a surprise.”
35

Volcker had promised a surprise and had delivered more than most CEOs wanted to see. He knew that a worried CEO could devote more resources to ensuring compliance than all the regulators money could buy. The financial columnist Floyd Norris quipped, “Certification concentrates attention.”
36

Volcker concludes, “I have strongly advocated that the CEO and board of directors of commercial banks personally attest to their firm's compliance with the legal restriction … To my mind bankers who contend that they cannot distinguish in practice between a continuing pattern of proprietary trading and trading in response to established customer needs cannot be considered either serious or qualified bank managers, no matter how many lawyers and layers of financial manipulation are employed to subvert the plain prohibition.”
37

He is right. CEOs of major financial institutions know the difference between speculation and market-making. They also have the internal controls to manage trader behavior. Regulators do not have the resources to restrain speculation at commercial banks by themselves. The Volcker Rule will work if regulators force bank management to make it work. Otherwise it will fail.

19. Trust

Gold, the ancient monarch of world finance, lost its crown in 1971, when President Richard Nixon ended foreign central banks' right to convert dollars into the precious metal.
1
Nixon followed Volcker's blueprint in administering the coup that began in Congress six years earlier.
2
Since then the world has been on a dollar standard, a fiat currency backed only by the full faith and credit of the United States. Dollars serve Americans as “legal tender for all debts, public and private,” but without a fixed link to any commodity.
3

Milton Friedman, an apostle of monetary rectitude, supported the overthrow of gold. He testified in Congress that the “gold reserve requirement is an anachronistic survival from an earlier age.”
4
Friedman echoed the famous denunciation of gold as a “barbarous relic” by the British economist John Maynard Keynes, and reflected the sentiment of most American economists alive when he testified. But he worried.

Friedman wrote that the worldwide experiment in fiat currency “has no historical precedent,” and cited the warning of Irving Fisher, the great U.S. monetary expert of the early twentieth century.
5
“Irredeemable paper money has almost invariably proved a curse to the country employing it.”
6
Friedman was less pessimistic than Fisher, who worried about hyperinflation, but not by much. “It is not possible to say whether Fisher's 1911 generalization … will hold true in coming decades.” It will
depend, Friedman said, on whether we “find a substitute for convertibility into [gold] that will serve the same function: maintaining pressure on the government to refrain from … inflation as a source of revenue.”

The 1970s nearly confirmed Irving Fisher's worst fears. Debate over the cause of the Great Inflation in the United States continues, but cannot dismiss as coincidence the removal of gold as the monetary anchor.
7
Congress might have prevented irresponsible monetary policy by refusing to adjust the gold reserve requirement, had it still been the law, the same way it occasionally refuses to raise the debt ceiling to extract fiscal concessions.

Volcker rescued the experiment in fiat currency from failure. His belief that price stability belongs in the social contract and that inflation undermines trust in government encouraged policies to restore monetary discipline during the 1980s. He showed that a determined central banker can behave like a surrogate for gold. But even Volcker needed help. His refusal to monetize federal deficits forced Congress to implement a plan for fiscal responsibility, reinforcing the Federal Reserve's credibility.
8
The combination brought decades of price stability to America and preserved trust in the U.S. dollar both at home and abroad.

The crisis that began in 2007 threatens that trust.

Foreigners hold dollars because America has demonstrated fiscal and monetary integrity, and because the United States is a nation of laws and markets, providing a safe haven for storing wealth. Broad, deep, and resilient financial markets that are free from manipulation and excessive regulation have allowed investors to commit and withdraw funds with ease and without challenge. Foreign appetite for U.S. securities has bestowed a gift of low interest rates on spendthrift Americans. But the need for massive government intervention during September 2008 tarnished the reputation of American finance. And the policies implemented since then harbor seeds of further damage.

The Federal Reserve, under the chairmanship of Ben Bernanke, served as lender of last resort during the fragile days and weeks following the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers on September 15, 2008. Congress established the Federal Reserve System in 1914 for precisely that purpose, to lend when no one else would to prevent the spread of financial
panic. And Bernanke deserves credit for avoiding a catastrophe like the Great Depression. But by mid-2011, though the overnight interest rate had been kept near zero for almost three years, and the banks had been provided with unprecedented liquidity, the economy had failed to recover fully and unemployment remained unacceptably high.

On Tuesday, August 9, 2011, the central bank announced that the FOMC had decided “to keep the target range for the [overnight] federal funds rate at zero to one-quarter percent [and] anticipates that economic conditions … are likely to warrant exceptionally low levels for the federal funds rate at least through mid-2013.”
9
The Fed's commitment to maintaining low interest rates for two years disturbed Volcker. “How can they know now what is appropriate for that length of time? They may be painting themselves into a corner.”
10

The 1970s taught central bankers two big lessons: Monetary policy can lower unemployment only temporarily, while inflationary expectations remain dormant, and inflationary expectations percolate to the surface even before the economy reaches full employment. Volcker brought that message forward with an op-ed article in September 2011: “The danger is that if, in desperation, we turn to deliberately seeking inflation to solve real problems—our economic imbalances, sluggish productivity, and excessive leverage—we would soon find that a little inflation doesn't work … What we know, or should know, from the past is that once inflation becomes anticipated and ingrained—as it eventually would—then the stimulating effects are lost. Once an independent central bank … invokes inflation as a policy, it becomes very difficult to eliminate.”
11

Expansionary fiscal policy, the Keynesian recipe for combating economic stagnation, shifts concern to the exploding federal deficit. But only the structural budget deficit that would prevail at full employment poses a problem, rather than the temporary increase in the deficit during recession. The increased borrowing required by cyclically declining income tax revenues, for example, reverses itself as the economy recovers, making room for corporate borrowing when it matters. In 2011, however, the full employment budget deficit was 5 percent of national output, a number reminiscent of the Reagan-era deficits, and that signals trouble.
12
The United States has thus far escaped the high interest rates that come with such unsustainable deficit spending because the
economy remains in recession and because investors in U.S. Treasury securities trust the American political system to curtail fiscal excess as in the past. But that trust demands action before it dissipates.

Long-term budgetary extravagance combined with a banking system brimming with liquidity threatens investors with inflation. Increases in real interest rates as the economy expands, Volcker's medicine during the 1980s, can preserve investor confidence by restraining private spending and by persuading Congress to legislate a balanced budget. But Volcker acted after years of inflation had galvanized public opinion behind him, while in the second decade of the twenty-first century, Americans have been weakened by recession and unemployment. The Federal Reserve may not have the public support it needs to act preemptively.

Inflation is ancient history to most Americans, like some medieval curse, but the risk of resurgence in a world of fiat currency demands vigilance. Volcker worries that the international financial system is especially vulnerable now, “when foreign countries own trillions of our dollars, when we are dependent on borrowing still more abroad, and when the whole world counts on the dollar's maintaining its purchasing power.”
13

A commitment to a full-employment balanced budget would confirm the fiscal integrity needed to neutralize the danger at the source. Nobel Laureate Thomas Sargent, Volcker's favorite rational expectations expert, said that central banks need help. “They cannot do it alone.”
14
Federal Reserve chairman Ben Bernanke delivered a similar message: “A large and increasing level of government debt relative to national income risks serious economic consequences … High levels of debt … impair the ability of policymakers to respond effectively to future economic shocks and other adverse events.”
15

Bernanke did not say that long-term budget balance sustains trust in the Federal Reserve's commitment to price stability. He did not have to. History delivers that message—courtesy of Paul Volcker.

Personal Records and Correspondence

Kindergarten report card, page 1
.

Kindergarten report card, page 2: having difficulty with numbers 5 and 9
.

Other books

Dance While You Can by Susan Lewis
The Stranding by Karen Viggers
Alice-Miranda at the Palace 11 by Jacqueline Harvey
Serenity Valley by Rocky Bills
Straightening Ali by AMJEED KABIL
Young May Moon by Sheila Newberry
Come and Tell Me Some Lies by Raffaella Barker
Heidi by Johanna Spyri
The Time and the Place by Naguib Mahfouz
Reckless Secrets by Gina Robinson